Greenhouse gases and their management

The perturbation in atmospheric trace gases (e. g., SO2, O3, CO, CO2, CH4, NO2, and CFCs, among others) is an important factor affecting climate change (Hopkin, 2007). In turn, climate change may promote changes in agricultural conditions that could have deleterious socioeconomic effects (Howden et al., 2007). Atmospheric trace gases have strong absorption bands in the infrared (IR) and interact with IR radiation emitted both by the earth’s surface and the atmosphere. This directly influences the thermal structure of the atmospheric environment and contributes to the greenhouse effect. Gases such as NH3, SO2 and their derivatives have lifetimes of only a few days, but they can have significant effects on the atmosphere (Begum, 2005). Emissions of N2O and CH4 are currently the dominant contributors. Although CO2 is the main greenhouse gas in terms of volume, others must also be considered. In agricultural practices, the main culprit is nitrous oxide (N2O), significant quantities of which are released from cultivated fields (particularly with the intensive use of fertilizers) (Snyder et al., 2009; Ceschia et al., 2010; Mander et al., 2010). Because N2O is >300 times more potent as a GHG than is CO2, even modest volumes can have significant impacts on the overall balance (Cherubini, 2010).

Harnessing the carbon sequestration capabilities of the terrestrial biosphere has been recognized as a potentially powerful, yet relatively low-cost, tool to offset carbon emissions (Dorian et al., 2006) and models for that purpose have been investigated (Werner et al., 2010). However, terrestrial carbon sequestration has been considered insufficient for meeting more than 25% of the CO2 emissions reductions that are globally required by 2050. Given that carbon sinks are the best currently available scenario, an emissions credit system has been established to provide CO2 emitters (companies or countries) with a means to satisfy the carbon liability associated with their release of carbon into the atmosphere. The emitter temporarily satisfies his liability by "storing" (for a fee) the equivalent carbon in a terrestrial carbon sink (such as a forest) (Sedjo & Marland, 2003). This concept is the application of the "willing-to-pay" principle within the international economic market. More simply, the right to emit CO2 (in the form of a carbon credit) is compensated for by growing biomass that will sequester an equivalent amount of carbon. The marketing of carbon credits has been organized to allow for rewarding activities that result in the "permanent" immobilization of CO2 in a nongaseous form. Ultimately, a carbon fee has been proposed that would be paid by industrial countries (in proportion to their emission contributions to GHG) to developing countries; these countries could then invest them in carbon mitigation practices (such as establishing or maintaining forest sinks) (Jones, 2010). The Kyoto Protocol is now legitimating activities such as revegetation, forest management, cropland management, grazing-land management, and also carbon sequestration in deep crustal layers (such as oil fields and deep saline aquifers) for trading with carbon credits (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change [UNFCCC], 2002). Principles of justice in proposals and policy approaches to avoided deforestation are also being pursued (Okereke & Dooley, 2010) through negotiations on Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and forest Degradation (REDD).

It has been estimated that the biological sink may attain a cumulative CO2 sequestration of 100 Gt over the next 50-100 years, with most of it in forest systems. This implies the capture of 10-20% from the anticipated net fossil fuel emissions until 2050 (Sedjo & Marland, 2003). However, carbon sequestered in the terrestrial biosphere may lack permanence. Forests may be harvested for timber that can be used to produce short-lived products or may be cleared for other purposes. Wild fires can release large amounts of sequestered carbon. Farmers may return to agricultural practices that release carbon that was previously captured. In that sense, terrestrial carbon sequestration may simply represent a delay in the flow of fossil fuel carbon to the atmosphere. However, economic incentives for carbon sequestration should increase permanent sequestration. That is, wherever and whenever there are incentives (payments) for carbon-sequestration services, one would expect more sequestration to occur than if no payments were made (Johnston & Holloway, 2007; Tollefson, 2008).

Carbon sequestration in living forests can be performed on lands with low productivity that are not suitable for agriculture or for intensive forestry and that are compatible with goals of biodiversity conservation over large areas. In contrast, to be economically viable, intensive crops for biofuels generally need land that is more productive. Intensive biofuel crops may compete with food production or even with the less-productive lands that are currently sheltering most of the earth’s biodiversity (Huston & Marland, 2003; Miles & Kapos, 2008). For example, this phenomena has been observed in Brazil, Indonesia and Malaysia, where cattle, soybean, sugarcane and palm oil may compete with standing forest (Darussalam, 2007; Laurance, 2007; Malhi et al., 2008; Stone, 2007; Venter et al., 2008). In Indonesia, this competition has disastrous consequences for wildlife. To resolve this problem, the Kyoto protocol and subsequent versions should include "wildlife credits" (in addition to carbon credits) to sustain wildlife and its buffering effect on human activities (Lovelock & Margulis, 1974). This strategy would have the advantage of recognizing the fundamental roles played by ecosystem services and to begin to account for them (Maler et al., 2008). New financial incentives are needed to act as a countervailing force to the economic pressures for deforestation (Jones, 2010). The recent agreement known as the "Bali Roadmap", which aims to extend the Kyoto Protocol beyond 2012, includes directives for providing compensation to rainforest-holding nations in exchange for control of deforestation and environment degradation. Such compensation could be managed either through international carbon markets or through voluntary funds. These directives have the potential to shift the balance of underlying economic market forces that currently favor deforestation by raising billions of dollars to pay for the ecosystem services provided by rainforests. However, to be effective they will require exceptional planning, execution and long-term follow-through. The new proposal also aims to reduce EU CO2 emissions by 30% by 2020 if a global climate deal is reached in international negotiations (if not, the cut will be 20%) (Schiermeier, 2008). The EU is also planning to protect its economy against carbon "dumpers" by applying leverage that aims to force companies that import goods from polluting countries to buy emissions permits (Barnet, 2008).

Typically, carbon-credit compensation funds are used in developing countries for establishing new long-term plantations (such as rubber trees or oil palm). One difficulty is that the actual goal of carbon sequestration can be negated in cases where the renter first illegally burns the original forest, earns the carbon-credit funds and subsequently establishes a new plantation that will never be as productive, in terms of carbon sequestration, as the original forest. In some regions, environmental crimes are not easily detected and may also not be "significantly" punished. Key recommendations to ensure the environmental sustainability of biofuels through certification (including international approaches and global monitoring) should help to control the process (Scarlat & Dallemand, 2010). Despite these problems, the carbon-credit market was stabilized as of 2007 and is not expected to collapse any further (Haag, 2007). The next few years represent a unique opportunity (perhaps the last) to maintain the resilience of biodiversity and ecosystem services (Malhi et al., 2008; Garcia-Montero et al., 2010; Hagerman et al., 2010).